Paul Dermine (PhD candidate in
EU institutional law, Maastricht University) and Diane Fromage (Assistant Professor of European Law, Faculty of Law,
Maastricht University)
EU Fiscal Governance in the post-crisis era: The start of
the reflection period and the European Fiscal Board’s first report
Recent events
suggest that the Eurozone may soon be entering a new phase of its short but
already tumultuous life. As the dust of the sovereign debt crisis starts
settling, and the continent slowly returns to growth, winds of change are
blowing across the zone, and EMU reform is back on the agenda and hence
ardently debated at EU
and Member
States level. The context is thus ripe to critically reflect on the
economic governance system the crisis has brought about, and on the actions
carried out by the EU institutions and the Member States within that setting.
This post offers to
do just that with regard to fiscal governance. As is well known, the crisis
precipitated a substantial upgrade of the rules making up the European fiscal discipline,
and an unprecedented strengthening of the surveillance paradigm in the field of
budgetary affairs. Since it entered into force, this new normative catalogue introduced
mainly by the Six-Pack
and the Two-Pack
reforms, as well as its main enforcer, i.e. the European Commission, have
attracted a great deal of criticism (from the European Central Bank (ECB), the
International Monetary Fund and some Member States).
The last blow came
recently, from the newly established European Fiscal Board (EFB), which did not
wait long before hitting hard. Indeed, the EFB’s creation was first announced
in the June 2015
Five Presidents report. The EFB was to ‘coordinate
and complement the national fiscal councils that have been set up in the
context of the EU Directive on budgetary frameworks. It would provide a public
and independent assessment, at European level, of how budgets – and their
execution – perform against the economic objectives and recommendations set out
in the EU fiscal governance framework. […Furthermore, s]uch a European Fiscal Board
should lead to better compliance with the common fiscal rules, a more informed
public debate, and stronger coordination of national fiscal policies.’ Its
Chair – the Dane Niels Thygesen (a former member of the Delors Committee) – and
its four members were designated at the end of 2016 when it hence started to
function.
In its first
annual report ever, published on 15 November, the EFB presents a mixed
picture of the current regulatory framework, and the Commission’s action as its
guardian. It focuses on three issues: an evaluation
of the implementation of the EU's fiscal framework, a review and assessment of the fiscal stance for the euro area as a whole,
and the identification of best practices
in the functioning of national fiscal councils. It concludes with some suggestions on the future evolution of the
EU’s fiscal framework.
In performing its
evaluation, the EFB in fact underlines three characteristics of the current
fiscal governance framework that will guide our analysis: its complexity, its
persistent asymmetry and the important discretion left to the Commission in the
application of the rules in place. It furthermore analyses the possibility of
centralized fiscal stabilization within the Euro area.
This report
constitutes a welcome opportunity to explore some of the main challenges the EU
fiscal governance currently faces, and to suggest potential reform avenues.
Such endeavour is
all the more timely as the reincorporation of the Fiscal Compact into EU law
and the review of the Six-Pack and Two-Pack reforms will constitute key
priorities of the upcoming December EMU package of the Commission. Such
political momentum will certainly offer broader opportunities to further
enhance and streamline the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), and the other
instruments making up EU fiscal governance.
Background to the EFB’s first report
Before proceeding
with an analysis of the EFB’s first report, a few reminders are in order. As is
well known, the crisis precipitated a fundamental overhaul of EU fiscal
governance. On the one hand, the procedural framework for fiscal surveillance
and coordination was substantially strengthened, most notably by increasing the
scope and intensity of the oversight exercised by the EU on national public
finances. On the other hand, the very substance of the fiscal rules Member
States are subject to was tightened and further expanded.
In a nutshell,
the fiscal targets are now defined more strictly, requiring stronger yearly
adjustment efforts from the Member States. If the deficit remains the central
criterion of the EU fiscal discipline regime, the debt criterion has been
further operationalized, and an expenditure benchmark was added. The reliance
on structural rather than nominal indicators has been further generalized.
These developments show the clear intent of the EU to exercise close and
continuous scrutiny over all aspects of national budgets, in order to enhance
their overall sustainability.
However, conscious
of the need to accommodate a range of contingencies, and eager to preserve a
certain room for flexibility, the Six-Pack reform has also multiplied the
escape clauses entitling Member States to derogate from their budgetary
obligations under certain circumstances (i.a. structural reforms
implementation, severe economic downturn).
The overpowering complexity of EU fiscal governance
Certainly, a major
shortcoming of this new normative body is its overwhelming complexity. In the
post-crisis era, EU fiscal discipline consists of a dense web of detailed rules
and sub-rules governing public debt, deficit and expenditure. Those rules
display a high level of prescription and specificity, and yet, are tempered by
an equally complex array of general escape clauses and potential loci for
flexibility and derogation. Further increasing the systemic intricacy of the
EMU fiscal discipline regime, the rules are spread over different EU
regulations and directives, partially replicated in international treaties and
national laws (which do not always fully overlap).
Against that
background, it is proven that national authorities struggle to understand the
exact rules they are to abide to, and the margin of manoeuvre they still enjoy
under the current framework. Such lack of clarity also undermines transparency
with regard to the rules’ ‘indirect’ addressees, namely the general public and
the markets, and may in the long run harm the efficiency of public oversight
and market mechanisms as enforcement channels of fiscal discipline in the EMU.
Quite obviously,
there is a strong need for simplification. Even the European
Commission seems to acknowledge that. Too many rules, too many operational
targets do not favor compliance, monitoring, enforcement and overall
intelligibility, thereby undermining the legitimacy of the EU’s actions. In
that regard, interesting proposals for reform are currently on the table.
Correctly positing that the ultimate aim of the EU fiscal regime is the
preservation of debt sustainability, IMF officials
and, although to a lesser extent, the EFB consider that the system would gain in
readability and overall efficiency if it were to revolve around one fiscal
anchor (the debt ratio instead of headline deficit) and one operational target
(possibly the ‘fiscal effort’ variable). In a similar fashion, a substantial
streamlining of the existing escape clauses would also appear necessary.
The structural asymmetry of EU fiscal discipline
Another important
issue inherent to the current regime is its structural asymmetry. From the outset, the SGP was designed as a tool to
correct excessive deficit and debt levels and tame profligate States. Its rules
and procedures are thus exclusively driven by that objective, and the crisis further
strengthened this focus. Conversely, the rules do not contemplate that States
may be too frugal. Under the SGP, surplus equals balance, and surplus countries
are under no parallel duty to bring their fiscal position back to equilibrium. As
an asymmetric construct, the SGP is one-sided, and toothless when it comes to
dealing with too ‘virtuous’ countries.
This has proven
particularly problematic over the last few years, as the Commission was seeking
to achieve a positive
fiscal stance for the Euro area, and sought to enjoin the few Member States
accumulating large budgetary surpluses (such as Germany, Luxembourg or the
Netherlands) to engage in mildly expansionary policies by using the available
fiscal space and boosting public investment. Under the current regime, such
injunctions are at best wishful thinking, and lack any kind of legal support in
the texts.
In our view, such
asymmetry ought to be corrected, especially at a time when Europe heavily
suffers from an investment backlog. Does this mean that an ‘Excessive Surplus
Procedure’ should be established? This would probably be a step too far. But if
the achievement of budgetary equilibrium is to be the ultimate rationale of the
SGP, its provisions should be amended so that when appropriate, fiscal
expansion too can be commanded.
How complexity and flexibility empower the European
Commission
The current
regime’s inherent complexity and flexibility,
combined with the conceptual indeterminacy of some of its founding concepts
(such as that of the output gap), have also created significant room for
administrative discretion, which the
Commission has been very eager to exploit. It is indeed impressive to note that
at any key stage of the surveillance procedure organized by the SGP (either
under its preventive or corrective arm), the Commission enjoys discretion and
needs to exercise judgement.
Under a supposedly
rules-based system, this appears to be problematic (to some extent at least),
and obviously comes at the expense of the predictability, even-handedness and
efficiency of the entire regime. The main risk is that certain choices of the
Commission may no longer be economically motivated, but founded on political or
ad hoc considerations that may run counter to the economic rationale underlying
the EMU fiscal framework. In that regard, one may for example mention the very
generous decision of the Commission that Italy was eligible to the ‘structural
reforms’ escape clause, or its lenient stance in the framework of the Excessive
Deficit Procedure against France, which was never stepped up despite the clear
insufficiency of the French consolidation efforts ('Because
it is France' was the main justification expressly advanced by Juncker).
The surprising
decision of the Commission in the summer 2016 not to impose sanctions (even
symbolic) on Spain and Portugal for failing to take corrective action in the
framework of their EDP, also shows that discretion may come at the expense of
enforcement and, ultimately, of compliance. This notwithstanding, it is clear
that a system of smart rules cannot do without a dose of flexibility and
discretion. In the future, the focus should therefore not be on trying to erase
the loci for administrative judgement, but on making sure that such judgement
is primarily driven by an economic, non-political rationale.
This might however
prove difficult as the Commission (also) needs to ensure that its actions
remain legitimate in the eyes of the citizenry in addition to guaranteeing the
EU’s fiscal stability and it arguably has to take account of the fact that its
decisions to impose fines on non-complying Member States can only be overcome
by qualified majority in the Council. Simplifying the normative corpus should nevertheless
help in pursuing this objective of economically-based decisions. The Commission
should also be more transparent on its methodologies, and consistent in their
application. On a different note, the risk of biased, political application of
the SGP by the Commission primarily comes from its current hybrid nature: “between
an independent executive agency and a political government”, as the EFB rightly
puts it (p. 63).
Such risk may be
mitigated by a stronger reliance on economic advice independent of short-term
political considerations. Where this input should come from remains to be seen.
Quite naturally, the EFB has already offered its services. On the face of it,
the EFB’s role is significantly different from that of national fiscal councils
since it is not bound to take an active role in the implementation of the EU
fiscal framework; rather it has to evaluate the Commission’s actions in this regard.
By contrast, even
if national councils in most cases do not issue decisions binding on their
governments, they have to produce or endorse macroeconomic previsions, they
declare the activation of the automatic correction mechanism etc. In its
evaluation, the EFB offers to endorse responsibilities closer to that of
national councils.
Finally, in an
attempt to further reduce discretion, EMU fiscal discipline could gain in
consistency, foreseeability and congruence if it were to rely on smarter
enforcement mechanisms by means of financial sanctions. Financial sanctions
have shown all their limits in the past. In our view, macroeconomic
conditionality, i.e. linking access to EU funds to (an almost) compliance with
the fiscal rules of the SGP, could be the way to go. It is already used under
the current
multiannual financial framework, although in a much limited way. The
pattern could be generalized under the next framework.
Towards a Fiscal Union?
Next to the issues
of complexity, asymmetry and discretion visible in the EU fiscal framework, the
question of centralized fiscal
stabilization also deserves attention. The Eurocrisis has brought out in
the open the founding insufficiencies of the rules-based paradigm, and the
necessity to transcend such approach by endowing the supranational level (the
EU or the Eurozone) with a fiscal capacity of its own is now clearer than ever.
This shift from
negative to positive fiscal integration could take the form of unemployment
insurance or investment protection, with the exemption of investments from
the golden rule or not. The introduction of a rainy-day fund – also envisaged
by the Commission
– could also be a possibility. In our view, such a fund could appear to be a valuable
option since it would function on the basis of accumulated resources regularly
paid by Member States which would have a direct incentive to follow SGP rules.
To this type of fund or an unemployment insurance the EFB however favors the
protection of investment, which admittedly should be guaranteed too; perhaps it
is also the least bold shift towards an unpopular Fiscal/Transfer Union.
Another possibility
could be the introduction of an EU
budget. Although the EFB acknowledges that this debate falls outside of its
remit, it provides its opinion ‘as economists involved in the analysis of
public finance more generally’ (p. 67), thereby arguably affirming its standing
in the more global EU financial area. The form this budget should take –
whether as a dedicated euro area budget (as recently suggested by President
Macron) or as a dedicated budget euro area budget line in the EU budget (as
envisaged by the European
Commission) – is left open; in the absence of a dedicated euro-area
parliamentary arena, perhaps the latter option is preferable to avoid further
increasing the European democratic gap.
Beyond this, such a
move would significantly go beyond the sole fiscal stabilization and adopt a
broader stance on fiscal policy. This move, which would in fact represent the
return to a perspective adopted at previous stages of the European integration
process, would indeed be particularly welcome as it would (eventually) provide
remedy to some of the shortcomings of the current fiscal policy design.
What does this report tell us?
This report is, in
our view, important for at least two reasons. First, it bears a valuable
assessment of the current EU fiscal framework as implemented by the Commission
at a time when reflections on the future of the Eurozone architecture are high
on the EU agenda. Second, it clears up certain doubts that could have existed
when the EFB was first established, in particular as to its capacity to provide
a truly independent assessment of the Commission’s actions. Indeed, concerning
the latter point, a certain degree of uncertainty existed in light of the close
ties between the EFB and the Commission, as well as in light of the absence of
the EP’s involvement.
Furthermore, the
EFB’s ability to act as an authoritative institution was not a given since it
was established as a completely new institution that hence had to first prove
its reliability (and independence). The content of the first report analysed
here appears to indicate that the EFB is likely to surpass both hurdles
successfully, at least as long as it is chaired by the prominent and respected
expert Niels Thygesen.
Concerning the
future of the EU fiscal framework, it certainly provides a useful and timely
assessment. It both highlights the weaknesses in the current fiscal framework
and in its enforcement by the Commission and makes a valuable contribution to
the debate on its reform; this contribution is all the more valuable as it
stems from the EU institution tasked with performing this assessment and not
from the ECB or the IMF as had been the case thus far. We will now have to wait
until the beginning of December to see if and how these proposals have been
picked up by the Commission.
Barnard & Peers: chapter 19
Photo credit: Supertrader
No comments:
Post a Comment