Angus MacCulloch, Lancaster University Law School
Two judgments on Articles 34/36 TFEU (concerning the free
movement of goods) handed down by separate courts in the same week give stark
examples of the importance of having a good evidence base before a State seeks
to justify a public health intervention in the market. The first example was
the judgment of the CJEU in Case
C-148/15 Deutsche Parkinson Vereinigung, a preliminary reference
considering the compatibility of a German measure setting fixed prices for
prescription-only medicines. The second being the judgment of the Inner House
of the Court of Session in Scotland in Scotch Whisky Assoc v LA [2016] CSIH 77,
where the court upheld the Lord Ordinary’s finding that the Scottish
Government’s plans to introduce Minimum Unit Pricing (MUP) for alcohol were not
contrary to Art 34 (following the CJEU reference in Case
C-333/14). Both measures involved health justifications for pricing
restriction measures that fell foul of Art 34, but the results were very
different.
Fixed Price
Prescriptions
‘The reasons which may be invoked
by a Member State by way of justification must thus be accompanied by an
analysis of the appropriateness and proportionality of the measure adopted by
that State, and by specific evidence substantiating its arguments’.
It was this final point on ‘specific evidence’ that proved
to be crucial in the case, as the Court went on to explain in [36].
‘that court must examine
objectively, through statistical or ad hoc data or by other means, whether it
may reasonably be concluded from the evidence submitted by the Member State
concerned that the means chosen are appropriate for the attainment of the
objectives pursued and whether it is possible to attain those objectives by
measures that are less restrictive of the free movement of goods’.
In the subsequent paragraphs the Court went through the
submissions of the parties and suggested that there was ‘no evidence to
substantiate the contention’ that the scheme was necessary to ensure a uniform
supply of prescription-only medicines [37]. In fact nothing before the Court
suggested that without the system mail order pharmacies, competing on the basis
of price, would threaten essential services, such as emergency care or
providing activities in the general interest; in fact competition might
encourage traditional pharmacies to improve such services [39-40]. The
assertion of the Court at [42] is perhaps the most telling:
‘it should be noted that the existence
of a genuine risk to human health must be measured, not according to the
yardstick of general conjecture, but on the basis of relevant scientific
research’.
Because of the failure to provide convincing evidence of the
effectiveness of the measure the Court found that it had ‘not been shown to be
an appropriate means of attaining the objectives relied on’ [45]. It had
therefore fallen at the 1st hurdle in the two-part test. As it was not shown to
be ‘appropriate’, there was no need to consider if it was ‘necessary’.
Minimum Unit Pricing
The Inner House (IH) in SWA were tasked with applying the
same two-part test, but this time the result was very different. The court’s summary
of the evidence presented by the Scottish Govt runs across many paragraphs, [125]-[143],
citing numerous studies, both domestic and international in scope. The
Petitioner challenged the conclusions and methodology of a number of those
studies, but the Scottish Government argued that the State had discretion and
it was not unreasonable that it would ‘prefer one body of evidence the other,
so long as the information which supported the choice was cogent’ [130]. As the
IH was acting in an appeal it confined its review, in the most part, to
confirming that the Lord Ordinary, in the Outer House, had correctly applied
the law. The first important, and perhaps the most important, question was to
confirm that the Lord Ordinary had identified the correct aim of the
legislation. Both the AG and CJEU, in the reference, had noted that the
legislation appeared to have a dual objective, whereas the Lord Ordinary had
focused on a particular aim; the reduction of alcohol consumption by harmful
and hazardous drinkers. The IH found that the Lord Ordinary’s particular view
was identical to that of the CJEU. That is perhaps surprising, as many
commentators had seen a different emphasis in the CJEU; suggesting that it had
struck some form of balance between the narrow goal of dealing with harmful and
hazardous drinkers, and the wider goal of reducing general alcohol consumption.
The IH implicitly rejected that interpretation of the judgment.
In its examination of the appropriateness of the measure the
IH noted the extent of the problem with alcohol consumption; the ‘societal,
family, and personal effects of excessive alcohol consumption in Scotland are
difficult to over-estimate’ [178]. This assertion was based on the ‘raft of
statistical material [which] was produced’ [180]. It also recognised the clear
view that the policy would target harmful and hazardous drinkers. It noted that
it was possible to attempt to rebut figures used in support of the measure, or
counter the conclusions drawn by the Govt, but that ‘there was and is ample
objective material to support the proposition’ [182], and, at [183], that:
‘the Lord Ordinary cannot be
faulted in finding that there was evidence from which it could be inferred that
minimum pricing was an appropriate method of securing the objective by tackling
the specific consumption of cheap alcohol’.
When turning to the proportionality of the measure the IH
considered the Petitioners preferred measure, the increase of general taxation,
which they argued would be ‘as effective’ as MUP. But that argument was
rejected; ‘[t]he fundamental problem with an increase in tax is simply that it
does not produce a minimum price’ [196]. The IH pointed towards evidence that
retailers have sold below cost or absorbed, or off-set, tax increases. Also
that price increases in the lowest cost products would ‘produce a greater
reduction in sales than across the board price increases’ [199], as trading
down to lower cost products was not possible. In fact a general taxation
increase would have, ‘disproportionate, undesirable and unnecessary effect on
moderate drinkers, who do not generally represent a significant problem in
societal terms’ [200]. Finally, at [204], the IH addressed the choice of 50p
per unit:
‘Such a figure, on the material
produced, will reduce consumption amongst harmful and hazardous drinkers in
that quintile of the population whose health is affected most by the
consumption of cheap alcohol. The benefits of this are well documented’.
On that basis the Inner House, upheld the findings of the
Lord Ordinary and refused the reclaiming motion.
One interesting feature of the case before the IH was that the
CJEU had made it clear in its preliminary reference that a domestic court
should address the proportionality of the measure at the time it gives its
ruling, not at the time the measure was adopted. As the original pleadings were
lodged in 2012 a significant amount of new evidence and policy material had
become available in the intervening period; including new evidence since the
CJEU judgment in the reference was handed down in December 2015. The IH took
note of the evidence that was considered by the Lord Ordinary, and the
subsequent proceedings, and decided that it was in the interests of justice
that any pertinent new material should be considered. But it stressed that the
new information would only be significant if it was such that it would have
altered the Lord Ordinary’s view of the facts. It was apparent that the new
evidence merely added to the exiting body of evidence that supported the
effectiveness of MUP as an intervention.
Conclusions
In a series of recent decisions, including, for example,
Case C‑639/11
Poland & Case
C‑61/12
Lithuania, the CJEU has begun to
stress the importance of evidence to support an attempt to justify a
restriction on free movement. In DPV we see that requirement given greater
emphasis, and a new focus on the type of evidence that will be required. It is
not sufficient for a member State to rely on mere assertion or conjecture. They
will have to produce more. The Court’s preference is clearly for hard
statistical or scientific evidence, although it will accept other forms.
Domestic courts are charged with ensuring that the State has good evidence to
support the appropriateness and proportionality those measures. The judgment of
the IH shows how that analysis can be undertaken. It also makes clear that the
analysis of proportionality is not an event, rather a process. If a policy
stands or falls by its evidence, it must therefore be the case that changes in
the evidence base can alter whether that measure is ‘appropriate’ and/or
‘necessary’ over time.
Barnard & Peers: chapter 12, chapter 16
Art credit: “Beer Street and Gin Lane”, William Hogarth
This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete