Angus MacCulloch, Lancaster University Law
School
Background to the Opinion
Advocate-General
(AG) Bot delivered his Opinion in Case C-333/14, ECLI:EU:C:2015:527, on 3
September regarding plans by the Scottish Government to introduce a Minimum Unit
Pricing (MUP) for retail sales in Scotland set at £0.50 per unit. Before it
could be introduced the measure was challenged by the Scotch Whisky Association.
At first instance the Scottish Government successfully defended their proposal,
in The Scotch Whisky Association & Ors, Re Judicial Review [2013] CSOH 70, but on
appeal the Inner House referred several questions to the CJEU: Scotch Whisky Association & Ors v The Lord Advocate [2014] CSIH_38. The
questions referred address the compatibility of MUP with both the single Common
Market Organisation (CMO) and the free movement provisions in the TFEU. The
AG’s Opinion has been hailed as a victory by both sides in the dispute, and on less
partisan examination it does give insight into the importance of price
competition to EU law.
The Compatibility of MUP with the single CMO
Article
167(1)(b) of the ‘single CMO’ Regulation, Reg 1308/2013, sets out
that Member States must not allow price fixing for wine. But the AG notes that
the provision is set out in the specific context of Art 167 which governs the
laying down of ‘marketing rules’ to regulate supply [33], particularly where
the rules are promulgated by stakeholder ‘interbranch organisations’. He
therefore found there was no direct
prohibition of retail price fixing in
the CMO, and Member States retained their shared competence on this issue.
He then
turned to the potential for indirect
prohibition through the Member States’ obligation not to jeopardise the
objectives of the CMO through Art 4(3) TFEU. The Commission argued that
regulating retail prices would be contrary to the principle of the free setting
of prices, by denying low cost producers the pricing advantages encouraged by
the CMO. At [36] the AG set out that: ‘the free formation of prices is the
expression … of the principle of free movement of goods in conditions of
effective competition.’ Minimum retail pricing in a Member State would
undermine low cost competitive advantage and distort competition, and is
therefore incompatible with the single CMO [38 & 39]. Notwithstanding this,
the existence of the CMO did not prevent Member States from adopting measures
which pursue ‘legitimate objectives’ such as the protection of public health
[40]. However, when pursuing such an objective, ‘the principle of
proportionality requires that the national measure must actually meet the
objective … and must not go beyond what is necessary in order to attain that
objective’ [44]. The proportionality analysis should be the same as used under
Art 36 TFEU, concerning possible Treaty-based limitations on the free movement
of goods.
The Compatibility of MUP with Art 34 TFEU
The first
notable aspect of the AG’s Opinion in relation to Art 34 (the ban on
quantitative restrictions or measures of equivalent effect – or MEEQRs – on the
free movement of goods) is that he undertakes an analysis of whether MUP is a
MEEQR, even though both parties to the dispute had accepted it was. Reconciliation
of the CJEU’s approaches in its previous judgments in van Tieggle, Keck, and Trailers is not easy. Can, after Keck, MUP be characterised as a ‘selling arrangement’ and fall
outside Art 34 TFEU in principle, effectively rendering the finding in van Tieggle otiose? The AG avoids the problem
by, at [58], adopting a hybrid approach which takes elements from all the
judgments, including the ‘market access’ test in Trailers, thus: ‘a national measure may constitute an obstacle not
only when, as a selling arrangement, it is discriminatory, in law or in fact,
but also when, irrespective of its nature, it impedes access to the market of
the Member State concerned’. If the measure hinders access there is therefore no
need to consider if it is discriminatory, because it will fall within the scope
of Article 34 in any event. He goes on to make clear that the loss of the
ability to exploit low cost competitive advantage is in itself a hindrance to
market access and brings MUP within the scope of Art 34 TFEU; effectively
contemporising van Tieggle reasoning
through the Trailers ‘market access’
test [60]. This is perhaps one of the most interesting suggestions in the
Opinion. It gives price competition special protection as a driver of free
movement within the internal market. The AG, for completeness, goes on to also
discuss whether MUP might be a dynamic selling arrangement (like an advertising
restriction), but his arguments [66-67], particularly those about domestic wine
production, are not very convincing.
Moving on to
consider the potential justification of a MEEQR under Art 36 TFEU, the AG first
discusses the discretion available to Member States when deciding on the level
of protection for a legitimate objective. He argues that the Member States must
be allowed discretion as range of policy choices could be taken in these
complex areas, but that Member States must adduce evidence to show that they
have made a suitable and proportionate choice [87]. The explanation of how the
analysis of proportionality should be undertaken, at [91]-[93], is, however,
not particularly clear. Para [93] is the most troubling, suggesting that the
national court should balance the ‘degree of impediment’ to trade against ‘the
importance of the objectives pursued and the expected gains’. Should a domestic
court be required to balance the benefits of trade against a public health
benefit?
When the AG
moves onto more direct consideration of MUP he examines a vital question in the
first instance judgment, which I have previously addressed elsewhere: the
identification of the particular aim of the measure. He suggests, at
[116]-[117], that there is an ‘ambiguity’ whether MUP’s aim is to tackle,
‘harmful’ and/or ‘hazardous’ drinking, or protect the health of all drinkers; it
is, however, acknowledged that the national court will have to take the final
decision on this matter. The AG does accept that in relation to harmful and
hazardous drinking, notwithstanding the complexities involved, it ‘does not
seem unreasonable’ that a Member State might consider MUP an ‘appropriate
means’ of attaining the objective [127]. He was also convinced by evidence
presented by the Lord Advocate regarding the particular impact of MUP alongside
other polices in relation to harmful and hazardous drinkers, particularly
amongst the young [135]. At this point you might think that the Lord Advocate
has won over AG Bot, but there is sting in the tail of the Opinion.
When it comes
to the necessity of the measure the AG is less convinced, especially when MUP
is compared with the alternate policy of a general increase in alcohol duty. At
first instance the Outer House of the Court of Session rejected a general
increase in duty because it did not effectively target the measure at harmful
and hazardous drinkers, as it would also have an impact on moderate drinkers,
and less problematic on-sales consumption. The AG is not convinced by the
argument that the measure is more targeted [147]. The key passage comes in para
[149]: ‘on the assumption that the objective of the rules … is genuinely
confined to combating the hazardous and harmful consumption of alcoholic
beverages … I consider that it is for the those responsible for the drafting of
those rules to show that increased taxation is not capable of meeting that
targeted objective.’ In itself that is not a controversial statement; the
burden of proof in such an instance is well established. But he goes on to add
another element: he argues the Lord Advocate would have to ‘adduce evidence’
that a general increase would have a ‘disproportionate impact’ on moderate
drinkers, and that it could also have a benefit in addressing harmful or
hazardous consumption in higher income groups who are less likely to be
effected by MUP. He also adds that a general increase might also have another
‘additional advantage’: a contribution to general health objectives. This might
‘constitute a decisive factor that would justify the choice of that measure
rather than the MUP measure’ [150].
To my mind
this is a false step at the end of the Opinion. Increases in general excise
duties have been the preferred measure in many of the Tobacco cases referred to
in the Opinion, but the problems of tobacco and alcohol consumption are very
different and suit different solutions. All tobacco consumption is bad, and all
consumption is essentially the same. That is not true of alcohol, even in
Scotland. Consumption in bars and restaurants poses very different problems
when compared to alcohol purchased for consumption at the home or on the
streets. Patterns of consumption of different types of product are also very
different. I am far more convinced that the targeting of the measure serves a
useful purpose. I am also still confused as to why a general increase in duty,
which by definition will impact on all consumers and all trade in alcohol, as
opposed to the limited impact of MUP, is seen as being less restrictive on trade. A general increase in duty must affect a
higher volume of trade if nothing
else. I suggest the push towards general duty increases is not really about
trade at all. Again we see a policy choice designed to protect price
competition in the market. The Tobacco Directives make their competition goal
explicit, but it appears that the AG is using Art 34 & 36 TFEU to achieve
the same result in the free movement sphere.
Barnard & Peers: chapter 12
As to the last point, that's what I was thinking too as I was reading (see Twitter for proof). I don't see how a MUP is so much more restrictive, if at all, that it isn't within the discretion of the legislature to adopt it. (There's a separate section earlier in the opinion about the discretion of policy makers, but that notion doesn't seem to have troubled the AG.)
ReplyDeleteOtherwise, I really don't like the suggestion that making it hard for cheaper producers to compete on price is somehow a restriction on trade. Surely that's a problem for cheap domestic producers as much as for cheap foreign ones? The fact that there is evidence that this minimum price will affect more imported products than foreign ones doesn't change that, I think. Restrictiveness is conceptual (absent evidence that a particular measure was intended to make life difficult for imports), and so restrictiveness shouldn't be determined by the conditions at the moment, which may well be different in a few years' time.
So if I had my way, I'd allow it under Keck, or otherwise as a measure that is sufficiently justified for public health reasons. But that's just me.
Hi Steve,
ReplyDeleteTotally off topic but can you clarify a question asked by one of my adherents. "Can you tell me, is there anything in this treaty which confirms the
removal of the UK's Sovereignty? I'm sure it does but it is a lengthy
document.". I would be grateful to hear your advice. Thanks in advance.
Nic Smith
Which treaty? The TFEU? Since the UK has the power to withdraw from the EU (and therefore that treaty) it is sovereign, in my view.
DeleteThanks Steve,
DeleteI was certain that was the case. It seems that there are certain people who believe that sections of the Lisbon treaty are worded in such a way that will allow removal of our sovereignty if we vote to remain in the EU. If you could, briefly clarify this for me, I would be grateful.
Yours,
Nic Smith
In my view the UK will remain sovereign as long as it has the power to withdraw from the EU. There's nothing in Article 50 TEU to say that such a vote could only be held once. Nor is the UK obliged to sign up to any future Treaty amendments, or the single currency, or to give up any of its other opt-outs if the UK public vote to remain in the EU. The argument that 'if we stay in, we will be bound to sign up to more EU integration' is grossly inaccurate and crass scaremongering.
DeleteThanks Steve,
DeleteI thought that was the case.
Regards
Nic
This comment has been removed by a blog administrator.
ReplyDelete